660
Views  查看
37
CrossRef citations to date
迄今为止的交叉引用
6
Altmetric
Articles 文章

Valuing public goods of the agricultural landscape: a choice experiment using reference points to capture observable heterogeneity
评估农业景观的公共产品:一个利用参考点捕捉可观察异质性的选择实验

, &
Knut Per Hasund,Mitesh Kataria & Carl Johan Lagerkvist
Pages 31-53 | Received 15 Mar 2009, Accepted 15 Apr 2010, Published online: 24 Nov 2010
第31-53页|接收日期:2009年3月15日,接受日期:2010年4月15日,在线发布日期:2010年11月24日

Abstract 摘要

The willingness to pay (WTP) for different types of elements and other environmental qualities of the agricultural landscape were investigated by a choice experiment study. To get value measures of a set of attributes as policy relevant as possible, the WTP for 28 levels of 12 attributes was estimated. Two survey versions concerned permanent grassland and two concerned field elements of cultivated land. A sample of 8000 randomly selected Swedish inhabitants was used. The estimated values vary significantly between linear field elements and grassland types, where stone walls and oak-wooded pastures, respectively have the highest marginal WTP. Highly valued environmental qualities are biodiversity, visibility and absence of brushwood. Reference points were included to capture preference heterogeneity. The study cannot reject that respondents may value environmental service levels based on their reference points.
通过选择性试验研究,探讨了农业景观中不同类型要素及其他环境质量的支付意愿。为了得到尽可能与政策相关的一组属性的价值度量,估计了12个属性的28个水平的支付意愿。两个调查版本涉及永久性草地,两个调查版本涉及耕地的实地要素。随机选择的8000名瑞典居民的样本。线性场元素和草地类型之间的估计值变化显着,石墙和橡树林牧场,分别具有最高的边际支付意愿。高度重视的环境质量是生物多样性、能见度和没有灌木丛。包括参考点以捕获偏好异质性。这项研究不能否认,答复者可能根据其参考点来评价环境服务水平。

1. Introduction 1.导言 

Agricultural land produces not only private goods such as food and fibre, but also positive externalities in terms of biodiversity, landscape scenery and other environmental goods. As agricultural technology and relative prices have changed, the supply of these environmental goods has declined drastically over the last century. Their public good characters of non-rivalry (Samuelson Citation1954, Randall Citation1988) and non-excludability (Randall Citation1972) imply that there are no prices or market incentives for the provision of these positive externalities, in spite of considerable concern in society. To attain the policy objectives, the European national rural development programmes involve agri-environmental payments directed to permanent grasslands and to elements of arable land (MA Citation2007a, Citation2007b, SBA Citation2007). These payments are, however, barely differentiated according to the range or the quality in environmental provisions of land and field elements. Lacking information about the marginal, social values of the environmental goods of the agricultural landscape may cause policy makers to misdirect public funds. Hence, access to such estimates appears to have a considerable potential for increasing the social efficiency of the policy.
农业用地不仅生产粮食和纤维等私人产品,而且在生物多样性、景观和其他环境产品方面也具有积极的外部性。随着农业技术和相对价格的变化,这些环境商品的供应在上个世纪急剧下降。它们的非竞争性(Samuelson 1954,Randall 1988)和非排他性(Randall 1972)的公共物品特征意味着,尽管社会相当关注,但提供这些正外部性并不存在价格或市场激励。为实现政策目标,欧洲国家农村发展方案涉及向永久性草原和可耕地要素支付农业环境费用(MA,2007年a,2007年b; SBA,2007年)。然而,这些付款几乎没有根据土地和农田要素的环境供应的范围或质量加以区分。 缺乏关于农业景观环境产品的边际社会价值的信息可能会导致决策者误导公共资金。因此,获得这种估计数似乎有很大的潜力提高政策的社会效率。

To meet that challenge, an aim of this study has been to estimate the marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) of the most policy relevant public good attributes of the agricultural landscape in Sweden.
为了迎接这一挑战,本研究的目的是估计瑞典农业景观的最相关的政策公共产品属性的边际支付意愿(MWTP)。

A foundation stone for our approach is that the agricultural landscape is heterogeneous. The heterogeneity refers to factors such as soil conditions, geographical location, biotopes, the objects' management history, surrounding landscape, frequency of visitors, type of objects and object size. It implies that the landscape services and their values vary considerably between objects. The complexity is further increased because a multitude of value motives about the landscape public goods are involved. Here they are divided into three main categories: biodiversity, cultural heritage and socio-cultural values. Socio-cultural values include scenery, accessibility and identity. As Randall (Citation2002, p. 305) noted: “… environmental economists have seldom if ever attempted a task so demanding as valuing the outputs of multifunctional agriculture”. Efficient agri-environmental payments have to be based on detailed and precise value estimates, which are measured on a national or continental scale, while the payments have to be implemented at the farm level (Randall Citation2002).
我们方法的基石是农业景观是异质的。异质性是指土壤条件、地理位置、生境、对象的管理历史、周围景观、游客频率、对象类型和对象大小等因素。这意味着景观服务和它们的价值在对象之间有很大的差异。由于涉及到景观公共产品的多种价值动机,使得景观公共产品的复杂性进一步增加。在这里,它们被分为三大类:生物多样性、文化遗产和社会文化价值。社会文化价值包括风景、可达性和身份。正如Randall(2002年,第305页)所指出的:“.环境经济学家很少尝试过对多功能农业的产出进行估值这样一项要求如此高的任务”。 有效的农业环境付款必须以详细和精确的价值估计为基础,在国家或大陆范围内进行衡量,而付款必须在农场一级执行(Randall 2002年)。

The agricultural landscape constitutes 10% of Sweden's surface area and has two official land use types: arable land and permanent grassland. In arable land, biodiversity, cultural heritage and aesthetic features are mainly related to linear field elements, such as stone walls or ditches, or to point field elements, such as ponds and field islets (Robertson et al. Citation1990, Ihse Citation1995, SBA 2005b, Citation2005c, Citation2006). Permanent grasslands are of three major types: traditional mowed meadows, semi-natural pastures and cultivated pastures, but within these are many subtypes.
农业景观占瑞典表面积的10%,有两种官方土地使用类型:耕地和永久草地。在可耕地中,生物多样性、文化遗产和美学特征主要与线性场要素有关,如石墙或沟渠,或与点场要素有关,如池塘和田岛(Robertson et al. 1990,Ihse 1995,SBA 2005 b,2005 c,2006)。永久性草地有三种主要类型:传统的割草草地,半天然牧场和人工牧场,但其中有许多亚型。

The traditional mowed meadows have declined from 1,900,000 hectares in 1890 to 12,000 hectares in 2002 in Sweden (SBA Citation2005a, Citation2005d). Together with the semi-natural pastures they are the species richest terrestrial habitats in Scandinavia (Svensson Citation1988) and are also considered the most valuable in terms of cultural heritage and recreational terms. The area of semi-natural pastures has declined to 229,000 hectares at present (SBA Citation2005a). According to Ihse (Citation1995) who made a survey based on aerial photos, more than 50% of the Swedish linear or point field elements were removed between the 1940s and 1990.
在瑞典,传统的割草草地从1890年的190万公顷减少到2002年的12,000公顷(SBA,2005年a,2005年d)。与半天然牧场一起,它们是斯堪的纳维亚物种最丰富的陆地栖息地(Svensson 1988),也被认为是文化遗产和娱乐方面最有价值的。目前,半天然牧场的面积已减少到229 000公顷(SBA,2005年a)。根据Ihse(1995)的一项基于航空照片的调查,在20世纪40年代至1990年间,超过50%的瑞典线性或点域元素被移除。

The environmental services of the agricultural landscape are not just a matter of quantity but also concern the quality of the grasslands and the field elements. Reduced grazing or labour intensive management and fertilisation or pesticide use have in many places caused overgrowth of brushwood, thickets and a vegetation of a few trivial, high grass species. Thus, the composition of flora and fauna species, the historicity, the visibility and the recreational access of the agricultural landscape have declined. Many species of the agricultural landscape are now threatened by the impoverishment of the grassland or field element habitats. For example, of 317 red-listed vascular plants in Sweden, 228 belong to the agricultural landscape (SSIC Citation2005). In all European countries, similar patterns of reduced agricultural landscape services exist because of lost grassland and field element objects or their deteriorating environmental quality (EEA Citation1995).

Not all landscape amenities are gone, however, and the Swedish environmental goal, ‘a rich cultivation landscape’, expresses high policy ambitions of preservation, stating “The value of the cultivated landscape shall be protected, while the biodiversity and the cultural heritage values are preserved and strengthened” (SEPA, Citation2006).

Without financial support, most of the permanent grasslands and field elements will nevertheless probably not be maintained or managed (Jonasson and Kumm Citation2006, SBA Citation2007), since as positive externalities they cannot be enforced by regulations. However, the authorities have little guidance to design socially efficient payment schemes. A contingent valuation (CVM) survey of Swedish residents by Drake (Citation1992) estimated the mean WTP of 975 SEK Footnote1/ha/y to protect agricultural land from spruce plantation. The respondents of the study were asked to assign preference points to allocate their stated WTP, which was interpreted so that the WTP for cultivated pastures was 1600 SEK/ha/y and for wooded pastures 2100 SEK/ha/y. The aggregated WTP of Swedish residents to compensate farmers for forbidding them to remove field elements was CVM-estimated by Hasund (Citation1998) to 4.7 billion SEK per year, corresponding to 1700 SEK per hectare of arable land on average. When asked to allocate value points according to what motivated their WTP, the respondents' disaggregated WTP was estimated at 200, 300, 250 and 110 SEK/y for cultural heritage, birds and wildlife, flora and accessibility, respectively. Another ranking in the study showed that the respondents gave stone walls 19 value points, ditches 12, traditional wooden fences 13, headland 3 and field roads 9 value points when disaggregating their WTP among types of field elements. There are also several, non-economic studies on how citizens or experts value the Swedish agricultural landscape, revealing large differences in value – by biological and other value concepts – between different land uses, field elements or environmental attributes (Hägerhäll Citation1999, SBA Citation2005a, Citation2005c, Citation2006, Citation2008).

Although of little relevance for Swedish policy makers because of the uncertainty involved in benefit transfer, some international CVM studies estimate various benefits of agricultural landscapes. Most of them, such as Bonnieux and LeGoffe (Citation1997), Bullock and Kay (Citation1997), Hanley (Citation1998), Santos (Citation1998), and Willis and Garrod (Citation1991), have focused on specific areas and accordingly, although they may be well suited for the problem addressed, they are hardly relevant for national policy purposes. A common approach, for example that of Garrod and Willis (Citation1995), has been to estimate the WTP of a uniform policy package, without complying with the suggestion by Randall (Citation2002) to be detailed and value functions rather than point estimates, or without giving marginal values necessary for optimal policy measures, Hodge and McNally (Citation1998). In such a CVM study, Colson and Stenger-Letheux (Citation1996) estimated the WTP for conserving the entire French agricultural landscape at 530 francs per year and household. Estimates of the value of shifting to a generally more environmentally friendly technology (see e.g. Young-Kwang and Chang-Gil 2006) suffer from the same lack of precision, not least since the same technology may generate different environmental benefits because of varying site conditions. Some studies do not attempt to estimate the total economic value, TEV, including non-use values. They measure only some of the use-values, mostly the recreational values, Pruckner (Citation1995) or Fleischer and Tsur (Citation2000).

To design efficient policy measures or measures that will be effective to obtain the established environmental goal is a complex task, considering the strong heterogeneity of the grassland and field element objects, implying that the social values of their landscape services differ considerably. Hence, there are several attributes to consider when designing the policy. Managing the agricultural landscape in line with public preferences calls for non-market valuation so that the benefits of the attributes can be estimated and compared with each other. The choice experiments (CE) method is particularly useful for such an assessment of several attributes. It avoids the part-whole bias of CVM, the yea-saying problem of dichotomous choice surveys, and can give marginal values of a consistent set of environmental characteristics (Hanley et al. Citation1998). In CE, the respondents reveal their preferences in a hypothetical setting by choosing their preferred alternative in a choice set (for reviews, see e.g. Louviere et al. Citation2000 and Alpizar et al. Citation2003).

To the best of our knowledge, only a very few studies have previously used the CE to estimate the benefits of agri-environmental attributes. Campbell et al. (Citation2006) used the method to estimate the benefits of eight landscape attributes in Ireland. They concluded that although further research is necessary, it is reasonable to assume that when the non-market benefits of landscape values are included, the total benefits of the agri-environmental schemes exceed the costs associated with them. Hanley et al. (Citation1998) conducted a CE study on Environmentally Sensitive Areas (ESAs) of Scotland for five types of landscape objects. The attributes could take two levels, for policy-on and policy-off scenarios, giving the ‘marginal’ WTP £6.7 for archaeology sites, £21 for wet grasslands and £11 for dry stone walls. They conclude that CE is more suitable for landscape policy design than CVM, not least with respect to benefits transfer. In a CE by Dachary-Bernard (Citation2004), 262 tourists of the Monts d'Arrée district made choices about three attributes, each at three levels. The WTP of integrating (hiding) modern farm buildings was €56/y per tourist household, and to have a bocage landscape with many hedges €46/y.

The remainder of the paper is organised as follows: section 2 presents the CE and its econometric model, section 3 the results with a sub-section 3.4 illustrating efficiency consequences, and section 4 concludes.

2 The choice experiment

2.1 A large-scale mail survey

This CE is designed to estimate the marginal values of 8 grassland types, 10 types of field elements and 9 agri-environmental quality attributes. In total, the MWTP for 28 attribute levels were estimated. The attributes were designed to be as policy relevant as possible.

The first phase of the study involved literature surveys, interviews and meetings to design and select the most policy relevant landscape attributes and their choice levels. Discussions with scientists of related disciplines and policy implementers at the responsible regional or national boards Footnote2 generated a list of candidate attributes. Then, by iterative ranking a final set of attributes was agreed upon by the research team in collaboration with the consulted experts.

An aim of the study was to develop a set of attributes covering the entire agricultural landscape in terms of object types and major quality aspects. Attributes were designed to cover all TEV-motive types Footnote3 to avoid the problems of partial analysis. To be as adaptable to varying site conditions and policy relevant as possible, the attributes were defined in terms of public goods, not in terms of any production technology.

Since the policy measures and the type of environmental services and qualities differ between permanent grasslands and field elements, the CE was divided into two separate surveys. The attributes and their levels are presented in and described more in detail below.

Table 1. Non-monetary attributes and levels of the surveys of field elements of permanent grassland.

The survey about permanent grassland was divided into two versions. Each version concerned five common attributes out of a total of seven. Five types of grasslands (open grazing land, shore meadow, oak-wooded pasture, birch-wooded pasture and dry meadows with junipers) were included. A binary experimental design was adopted for these objects as there was no prior consensus on which type to use as a baseline. In the permanent grassland surveys, levels of the environmental quality attributes were stated in absolute terms (e.g. given amount of brushwood, or given number of red-listed species).

The field element survey was also divided into two versions with, respectively, one unique attribute and three attributes that were common to both versions. Version 1 had type of linear field elements as a design specific attribute, while the version 2 had type of point elements as a unique attribute. The three common attributes (biodiversity, cultural heritage and visibility characters) were each stated at two relative levels of magnitude (i.e. more or less). The use of relative levels was viewed as more intuitive by our focus groups than the use of levels expressed by percentages or absolute numbers. Applying this attribute design approach, the biologists and policy implementers may then interpret what corresponds to ‘More biodiversity’ with respect to all variables of species composition, landscape context, region, etc.

Every respondent received an introductory letter, a fact folder and a questionnaire. In the introductory letter the respondents were briefly presented with the background and aims of the study from environmental, policy and fiscal perspectives, as well as matters of confidentiality. The fact folder presented first attributes and the respective choice levels by short texts and photos, with wording and motives as neutral and balanced as possible. The questionnaires had three sections. The first had questions about the respondent's relationship to the agricultural landscape, the second section had the CE, and the third had questions about the respondent's socio-economic status. Throughout the questionnaire, the respondents were reminded they had to consider their budget constraints as the choices involved increased income taxes. To reduce the probability of a hypothetical bias, we adopted the cheap-talk script from Carlsson et al. (Citation2005). The choice sets were created simultaneously in that the design was selected from the collective factorial (Louviere Citation1988). From the full collective factorial, we used the D-optimal linear design routine in SAS (Kuhfeld Citation2001) to select 36 choice sets. These were then randomly blocked into four versions, each containing nine choice sets. Footnote4 Each choice set had two alternatives. The CE did not include any opt-out alternative, that is, a possibility to choose ‘Neither alternative 1 nor 2’ or to choose a ‘Don't Know’ (DK) option, in the choice sets. However, since we were primarily interested in estimating the marginal WTP of the attributes, this would be an appropriate design. Footnote5

There are several potential disadvantages of including an opt-out or DK alternative. Even though it is argued that the use of opt-out or DK alternatives will recognise respondent behaviour or respondent uncertainty it can, on the other hand, be used as ‘an easy way out’ by respondents facing a complex and difficult choice task or a choice set that does not contain enough distinct options. A similar type of escaping by the opt-out alternative could possibly be expected in a CE where respondents exhibit lexicographic preferences. This is possible if, for example, respondents have preferences for levels of landscape attributes that are higher than those included in the choice set. A further problem is that respondents who would choose an opt-out alternative may be different from those making trade-offs between attributes, in the sense that they make different trade-offs on the margin. If this was the case, then an opt-out option would indeed affect the marginal willingness to pay as well.

The CE was carried out by mail surveys following the standard procedure with testing by focus groups and a pilot study of 500 randomly selected inhabitants in Sweden. All questionnaires were sent out in the spring 2008 to a sample of 8000 men and women, aged 18–75, randomly selected from the Swedish census registry. Two reminders were mailed at two-week intervals to those who did not reply. For the surveys about field elements of arable land, a total of 1163 respondents (29%) returned valid questionnaires. For the meadow and pastureland surveys, the response rate was 1474 respondents (37%). Footnote6

2.2 Reference points capturing observable respondent heterogeneity

In our econometric models, we separate the respondents who are accustomed to certain states of the agricultural landscape corresponding to attribute levels of the experiment, from those who are not, using dummy variable interactions. For example, some respondents may often visit grazing land with much brushwood. We then include this information into the econometric model and distinguish these respondents from other respondents. Their marginal utility of reducing brushwood is estimated separately.

This way of treating the respondents is partly influenced by the prospect theory of Kahneman and Tversky (Citation1979) that highlighted a body of evidence that strongly supported the existence of reference-dependent utilities. Footnote7 Reference dependency implies that the value that somebody assigns an attribute is not based on its absolute level, but rather on its deviation from a reference level. It leads to a sharp contrast between conventional and reference-dependent utility theory. The reference point might, for example, depend on past consumption, expectations or status quo. Unlike the conventional consumer theory, reference-dependent consumer theory also allows an individual to be loss averse, i.e. the value (utility) function is steeper for losses than gains. Moreover, a person may prefer attribute 1 to attribute 2 if she is endowed with 1, but may prefer 2 if endowed with 2. In another form, the value of a good to an individual increases when the good is in the individual's possession (endowment effect). This also explains features such as opt-out bias, i.e. a strong disposition for the status quo alternative. Footnote8 In a recent CE study, Hu et al. (Citation2006) found that reference dependency is important to understand consumers' choice of bread products, particularly with regard to understanding the effect of prices.

A challenge in modelling reference dependence is the identification of relevant reference points for each respondent. In our application, the reference point will be defined by the attribute and levels that are present in the agricultural landscape that the respondent most often visits, i.e. features with which the respondent is familiar. These attributes can be argued to serve as a natural point of comparison for the respondents (Samuelson and Zeckhauser Citation1988, Bruce et al. Citation1993). Footnote9 The use of a system of reference points based on familiarity with the subject to be valued should also mitigate the use of recognition heuristics, i.e. that respondents make inferences from patterns of missing knowledge (Goldstein and Gigerenzer Citation2002). We do not, of course, exclude other possibilities than that the respondents make their choices in the CE based on the attributes that they are accustomed to and value the alternatives based on deviation from their reference levels. They may visit different agricultural landscapes because of different preferences, although it has nothing to do with reference-dependency. Both of these interpretations are plausible.

To conclude, there are a number of reasons for including reference points in the econometric model. First, any way to decrease the magnitude of the noise term in the econometric model will in turn improve the statistical properties of the model. Second, including reference points could help to better understand the choices of the respondents, in terms of explanations given in the reference-dependent consumer theory supplementing conventional consumer theory literature.

2.3 Econometric model

In the econometric analysis we apply a random utility model. The utility consists of a systematic component (Vnjt ) and a random component (ϵ njt ):

where Unjt is respondent n's utility of choosing alternative j (j = 1, 2) in choice situation t (t = 1, … , 9). The systematic part of the utility can be expressed as β′xnjt , where xnjt is a vector of observed variables. Alternative i is chosen over alternative j if Unit  > Unjt , hence
The latent function U* can be interpreted as general index functions or as utility functions. To also account for unobserved heterogeneity in taste, we allow taste to vary in the population by assuming that the coefficients vary randomly among respondents in the CE. The utility function can be decomposed and written as:
where is the population mean and is normally distributed in the population with mean b and covariance W. Notably, the last two terms in the utility function are random, meaning that . Using this specification (i.e. random parameter logit), we obtain the population mean and the individual deviations from the population mean of the random parameters in the model. We assume that all the attributes of the CE are randomly and independently normally distributed except for the coefficient of the cost attribute, which is assumed to be fixed. Keeping the cost coefficient fixed, the distribution of the WTP is the same as the distribution of the attribute coefficient. Footnote10 Furthermore, we assume that randomly distributed parameters are constant across the choice situations for each individual. This reflects an underlying assumption of a stable preference structure for all individuals across the CE (Train Citation2003).

The model is estimated with simulated maximum likelihood using Halton draws with 500 replications using Nlogit 4.0 (see Train Citation2003 for details on simulated maximum likelihood and Halton draws).

3 Results

The estimates of this study are consistent with other landscape valuation studies in that their values are the same order of magnitude (see e.g. Drake Citation1992, Hanley et al. Citation1998, Hasund Citation1998, Willis et al. 1995), although there is no previous study of direct comparison. Considering the property right situation and the survey choice conditions, the estimated values of the study are Hicksian equivalent surplus measures, see Freeman (Citation2003).

3.1 Values of field elements in the cultivated landscape

presents the estimated models for linear elements and point elements, respectively. The alternative specific coefficients (ASC) are positive and significant in both versions, meaning that respondents are more likely to choose alternative 1. The ASC captures systematic but unobserved effects of choosing alternative 1; however, as this is a generic CE we do not expect this effect to be extensive. Since all the other attributes, besides one, are coded as dummy variables, we can directly relate the magnitude of the intercept to the dummy coded attributes. Although the ASC are statistically significant, they are small compared to the other coefficients; hence, they do not drive the model results.

Table 2. Results of the random parameter model on field elements of arable land. Estimated attribute coefficients and their standard deviations (p-values in parenthesis).

The coefficients for the design specific attributes are significant, except for Headland, Field islet and Pollard, with expected signs. Furthermore, the value motive attributes (biodiversity, cultural heritage and visual characteristics) have significant coefficients of the expected positive signs. The cost coefficient is negative and significant, as expected. The interaction terms of the cost coefficient were rejected for our data, indicating that the marginal utility of income is constant across income groups. Most of the estimated standard deviations of the random parameters are significant. The significance is a sign of heterogeneity in preferences among the respondents.

A way to make the estimates of the two survey versions comparable is by estimating the WTPs of the attributes. The MWTP of an attribute is obtained by dividing its estimated coefficient by the cost coefficient (Hanemann Citation1984). Hence, the MWTP is simply the marginal rate of substitution between one of the attributes and the cost attribute. The reference point effect is included when calculating average MWTP according to the sample share of the respondents that had identified reference points. The MWTP for the attributes in the field elements surveys are presented in . Most of the standard deviations are sizeable, compared to the attribute coefficients. This results in rather wide distributions of the MWTPs, as demonstrated below.

Table 3. Marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) in SEK per year for linear and point field elements of arable land, and for environmental quality attributes of such objects (90% confidence interval in parenthesis).

The ranking is in accordance with experts' judgements (see e.g. SBA Citation2008), but this study also contributes with monetary estimates of the differences in value. Stone walls are the highest valued type of linear field elements. Their MWTP is 240 SEK per year, meaning that people on average are willing to pay this extra tax amount to get a landscape with this linear element. Field roads are MWTP-valued to 168 SEK/y and traditional wooden fences to 147 SEK/y. Lowest values are assigned to ditches, whose MWTP is 101 SEK/y, and headlands, whose MWTP is 54 SEK/y. Ditches may, besides giving variation to landscape scenery and providing biodiversity or historic qualities, be associated with wetlands draining and the replacement of natural rivulets, which may explain their relative low MWTP value. Headlands are mere strips of vegetation along the fields, and thus provide fewer environmental services than the other linear elements, which always have such strips along their other features. The ranking of linear element values is identical to the CVM preference ordering by Hasund (Citation1998), except that the respondents of that study valued ditches higher than field roads.

Linear elements with more biodiversity are worth 390 SEK per year more (in terms of MWTP) than elements with little biodiversity. That biodiversity is the policy objective most highly valued agrees with earlier landscape valuation studies (Drake Citation1992, Hasund Citation1998). ‘More visible’ linear elements are worth (MWTP) 317 SEK per year more than less visible elements. Swedish residents apparently value aesthetic and other visual characters. This latter result is striking and obviously contrasts with valuations made by influential ecologists and persons involved in the policy process, who have disregarded visual landscape characters in favour of biodiversity and to some extent cultural heritage qualities; see Dramstad et al. (Citation2006), SBA (Citation2006), MA (Citation2007a), Sandström and Klang (Citation2007). The MWTP for linear elements that have more cultural heritage qualities is 190 SEK per year, which is considerable compared to the present agri-environmental payments.

With regard to types of point field elements, there are fairly small differences of the estimates. The MWTP values range between 120–180 SEK/y for the four most common Swedish types, which is considerably higher than the present payments. The result should be interesting in a policy context. Notably, however, pollards have a low but negative and not significant MWTP value. This result may be either because most people are unfamiliar with pollards as they are now less common, or that a pollard is small and gives fewer environmental services. The MWTP for the quality attributes of point elements are similar to those of the linear elements.

In general, the respondents have a higher MWTP for the environmental quality attributes than for the element type attributes. This implies that people are willing to pay to preserve field elements, and value elements having more biodiversity, visual or cultural heritage interest considerably higher than those lacking these attributes.

The confidence intervals of the MWTPs presented in are wide. They are calculated by the method outlined by Hensher and Greene (Citation2003), where both the mean and standard deviations from the RPL model are incorporated. Randomness across individuals as well the randomness introduced by the fact that both the central tendency and the dispersion of each parameter are themselves estimated quantities, and therefore subject to noise, are included. Substantial preference heterogeneity is revealed where some persons like and other dislike an attribute.

3.2 Values of permanent grassland

presents the estimated models for the surveys related to permanent grasslands. The ASC are insignificant in both of the grassland survey versions. All the attributes have the expected signs and the estimates are all significant, except for the attributes ‘Shore meadow’ (in both survey versions), ‘Oak-wooded pasture’ (one survey version) and ‘Landscape context’ (one survey version). About half of the estimated standard deviations of the random parameters are significant, although there is less evidence of heterogeneity in preferences for these models than for the field element models. Furthermore, the standard deviations of many attributes are sizeable compared to the attribute coefficients. This may indicate considerable preference heterogeneity.

Table 4. Results of the random parameter model on permanent grassland. Estimated attribute coefficients and their standard deviations (p-values in parenthesis).

The cost coefficient is negative and significant as expected. With regard to the field elements model, the marginal utility of income seems to be constant across income groups in survey version 2. However, survey version 1 shows a decreased level of disutility with increased income, although the magnitude of this effect is quite small.

displays the MWTP values obtained from the estimated grassland models. The marginal utility of the different types of grassland are estimated compared to the grazing land type ‘Dry meadow with junipers’, since it was the lowest valued in the surveys. The types of meadow or pasture are valued differently. Oak-wooded grassland is the most highly valued and has a mean MWTP in the range 120–340 SEK per year, depending on the valuation context. Grasslands with scattered oaks are symbols of a rich landscape, often with a high biodiversity and in many contexts recognised for their aesthetic or recreational qualities. The two survey versions consistently rank Oak-grown pasture at the top, followed by Open grazing land, Birch-grown pasture and Shore meadow lowest. Shore meadows have relatively low values – the MWTP ranges from 30–100 SEK/y. The result deviates from the general valuation of ecologists (see e.g. SBA Citation2008), particularly ornithologists, and the implicit valuation by policy measures (MA Citation2007a, Citation2007b), which assigns high values to many shore meadows.

Table 5. Marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) in SEK per year for permanent meadows and pastures, and for environmental quality attributes of such objects (90% confidence interval in parenthesis).

The three land use types ‘Traditional mowed meadow’, ‘Semi-natural pasture’ and ‘Cultivated pasture’ are different with respect to biodiversity, historicity and aesthetic qualities, besides the differences following grassland type, discussed above. Cultivated grasslands have been fertilised or sprayed with pesticides at least one time, which reduce their biodiversity, historicity and the scenic amenities of flowers for many decades or more. The MWTP of semi-natural pastures and traditional mowed hay meadows is, respectively, 224 SEK/y and 89 SEK/y higher than that of cultivated grassland.

An environmental status attribute that is relatively highly valued is whether the grassland is maintained either by high grazing pressure or by mowing with removal of the cut grass. Much grazing or mowing gives a low grass sward and no accumulation of organic litter, which favours biodiversity, the site's historicity, recreational accessibility and aesthetic features. If the pasture is not grazed, the ground vegetation becomes dominated by a few trivial species of high grass and herbs, organic litter accumulates, so that biodiversity, cultural heritage and aesthetic qualities are affected and the object becomes less traversable for visitors. The MWTP of ‘Some grazing’ is estimated at 132 SEK/y, relative to the status of ‘Not grazed or mowed’). ‘Much grazed or mowed’ is valued by an additional 133 SEK/y in MWTP.

Valued even more highly is the grassland property of not being covered by brushwood or thicket. The MWTP for meadows or pastures with 10% of its area covered is 172 SEK/y relative to the WTP for grasslands with more than 50% of its area covered, and with no brushwood or thicket an additional 114 SEK/y. Brushwood and thickets are signs of abandonment or long periods of little management, which may be symbolic to persons who object to the decrease of agricultural land and landscapes. They reduce visibility, recreational accessibility, biodiversity, historicity and aesthetic qualities.

Grassland objects vary considerably with regard to biodiversity. One measure of the biodiversity is the number of red-listed species an object accommodates. Grassland with three red-listed species represents objects with high biodiversity, but not exceptionally high. Its MWTP value is 179 SEK/y, compared to the value of grassland without red-listed species. The MWTP is 194 SEK/y for grassland with ‘six red-listed species’, representing objects of biodiversity top class.

Of highest interest in the preservation and policy debate recent years in Sweden is the ‘landscape perspective’ issue; see e.g. MA (2003) or Miljömålsrådet (2008). This issue refers to the value of an object in the context of its size and surrounding landscape. Ecologists claim that many pastures have become too small or isolated, so that several of their species do not exist in long-term sustainable populations (Young and Clarke Citation2000). For other species, the ‘last’ remaining meadow or pasture may be a spreading point in the landscape (Öckinger and Smith Citation2007). For cultural heritage and recreation, large objects in ‘traditional’ landscapes with many similar objects are considered to be generally more interesting (SNHB Citation1999). The MWTP value of ‘large grassland objects surrounded by other similar grounds’ is 103 SEK/y higher than that of ‘small and isolated grassland objects’.

Another intensively debated policy issue concerns how to allocate the scarce public means. It has been questioned both to direct the support to remote meadow and pasture objects having a rich flora or fauna but hardly any visitors, as well as the support to much visited grasslands close to cities which are more or less void of biodiversity or historic interest. Relating the issue to TEV-components, it concerns use and non-use values, which are additive. To our knowledge, the MWTP of use values assigned to grassland objects have not been estimated in other studies. In this study, one of the designed choice attributes was ‘How much you experience the grassland object’. The MWTP for ‘Grassland that you will be in contact with only rarely’ is 96 SEK/y, whereas the alternative ‘Meadows or pastures that you often visit or see’ have a MWTP of 235 SEK/y/p. The baseline in either case was ‘Grasslands that you will probably never see’. If aggregating over the population, the high use-values do not necessarily mean that little visited grasslands with high biological or cultural heritage qualities have a lower total value, since the number of persons who assign non-values to it may be large.

In general, the wide confidence intervals in of the MWTPs are striking and a sign of substantial preference heterogeneity.

3.3 Reference points – familiarity affects preferences

Parameter estimates for the interactions between attribute levels and reference points are reported in the last sections of and , respectively. In the permanent grassland survey, we distinguish between respondents that did answer the questions about reference points considering grazing and brushwood from those that did not (i.e. marked with No Ref. in ), since not all of the respondents responded to these reference point questions. Our findings suggest that the reference-dependent utility theory appears to explain some of the heterogeneity in the preferences for agricultural landscapes, or, such explanations can at least not be rejected. In total, approximately half of all the reference point effects were significant in the econometric models. The results indicate that the preference for a specific attribute level is positively related to a prior reference with respect to a specific characteristic of the attribute, given that the estimate of the reference interaction is significant.

In the field element surveys, all of the coefficients of the interactions between the attributes and the reference points are positive; however, not all of these effects are significant. There is a significant reference point effect for the attributes Wood fence, Stone wall, Headland, Field road, Field islet and Pond. In short, people who are familiar with these elements are more likely to appreciate them than others.

A result from the grassland surveys is that the marginal disutility of brushwood is significantly lower for respondents who often visit pastures with the highest level of brushwood. Similarly, those who often visit pastures with high grass vegetation find them less inferior than other persons do, and will in general be willing to pay less for more intensively grazed pastures than other respondents. On the contrary, persons who are accustomed to meadows and pastures with low grass or without brushwood are not willing to pay more than other persons to get this environmental status instead of grassland with some high grass or 10% of the area covered by brushwood.

The marginal WTPs are for some of the grassland types driven by reference points, but for other types this is not the case. Respondents who often visit shore meadows or birch-wooded pastures, for example, are willing to pay for them, while the WTP of the remaining respondents is insignificant.

One interpretation of our findings is that persons who do not care about some landscape characters as much as other persons are more apt to visit such landscapes, for example, pastures having much brushwood. Even if this were true for some of the respondents, it should also be borne in mind that people's choice of what type of agricultural landscape to visit can be based on many other factors, including distance from home, accessibility, recommendations of friends etc. Consequently, an alternative interpretation would be that respondents find brushwood less bad as they become surrounded by and accustomed to it. It may then serve as a reference-point to them. While the former explanation can be interpreted in the light of conventional utility theory, the latter leans more to reference-dependent utility theory where individuals evaluate outcomes based on departures from a reference point. As it is not possible to distinguish reference-dependency from conventional preference heterogeneity in this case, we should be open to both of these interpretations.

3.4 Social values versus actual payment tariffs

Our CE-attributes have been designed to be applicable as criteria for agri-environmental payments. It might then be interesting to compare the estimated values, expressing the marginal values to society of the attributes, with the actual, present grants. It shows, for example, that traditional wooden fences are currently remunerated higher than headlands, by 60 and 6 SEK per 10 metres, respectively. The former is likewise more highly valued by the Swedish population, with an estimated MWTP 150 SEK compared to 54 SEK for headlands. The figures for the case of point field elements are listed in . Comparing the figures reveals that the actual payments are little correlated with the marginal WTPs of the point elements. Consider also that the payments are conditional Footnote11 and uniform for each element type. Contrastingly, the MWTP vary across the types of point elements (and a lot more across types of linear elements or grassland). Furthermore, their social values are considerably different also within each type, since a single object may have more or less biodiversity, cultural heritage or visibility qualities. If highly endowed in all these respects, a certain point element object is in the extreme valued 830 SEK more than another element of the same type.

Table 6. Point field elements, the actual payments of the Rural Development Programme, the total number of point elements on arable land in Sweden, and estimated marginal willingness to pay (MWTP).

The divergence between actual payments and the marginal WTPs estimated for grasslands is also striking if making similar comparisons. A pasture with, for example, 10% of its area covered by brushwood or thickets is worth 170 SEK less than if it had not, but will get 1100 SEK/ha less in the existing AEP-scheme, i.e. 0 SEK. On the other hand, a semi-natural pasture that is in the vicinity of some housing area and has a lot of visitors gets the same payment as a cultivated pasture in a remote area where just a few persons enjoy it, although our estimations indicate that its marginal value to society is about 560 SEK higher, ceteris paribus. It is evident that the differentiations of the actual Swedish AEP-schemes in some cases are too high and in others too low relative to the estimated MWTP.

4 Concluding discussion

The general pattern in industrialised countries of decreasing environmental services from the agricultural landscapes becomes a problem in a welfare economic sense if society values these services more than what it would cost to provide them at the margin. Their character of non-rival or non-excludable goods produced by agriculture normally calls for some type of agri-environmental support to get the landscape amenities that are demanded. Uniform payments, cross-compliance directives, etc. do risk becoming inefficient, however, since these landscapes are quite heterogeneous in many dimensions. The long-term incentives to the farmers then become distorted and the resources become misallocated, implying an increased risk of inefficient abandonment and inefficient land management. A policy working towards social efficiency would require information about how much people value the respective elements and other environmental attributes of the landscape.

The findings of this study suggest that CE can be a useful tool for providing specific value measures of a set of environmental attributes also in the context of complex landscapes. It has been possible to attain the MWTP values of policy relevant landscape services, as identified by policy makers and scientists. In this CE-study, a large sample of Swedish inhabitants have expressed that their preferences differ between types of permanent grassland and between types of field elements, as well as between their environmental qualities. A stone wall is valued two-and-a-half times higher than a ditch, for example, and the MWTP for pastures or meadows having three red-listed species is 180 SEK higher than for those that do not, ceteris paribus. Of particular interest, there are considerable use values assigned to permanent grasslands. This suggests that there is a spatial component involved in forming private preferences for landscape attributes. Proximity, visibility or accessibility may have significant importance in establishing the MWTP for grasslands. The rather low response rates, as well as the degree of heterogeneity found in our empirical estimates, are factors that should be considered before adopting our results for potential policy design.

Our results further indicate a ranking of the types of elements and the environmental qualities of the landscape more or less in line with the ranking of non-economists experts and policy decisions (see e.g. SBA Citation2005a, Citation2008), and the landscape evaluations of the county boards. In some cases, however, our ranking is different. Birch-wooded pastures are popular and its private MWTP is found significantly higher than that of shore meadows, but the latter are generally more highly valued by biologists (see SBA Citation2005a, Citation2008). Another example is stone walls whose MWTP is the double that of traditional wooden fences, but implicitly valued the same by the policy payments. For most attributes, however, although the ranking may be consistent, there is a discrepancy between the size of the estimated MWTP in this study and values settled by other sources, to the extent that these are transferable into cardinal scales or monetary terms. As described above, the agri-environmental payments by the present rural development programme are little differentiated to value, if at all.

The findings of large divergence between private preferences for landscape attributes and agri-environmental payments implies that even a modest adaptation and differentiation of the payments could lead to a significantly more socially efficient landscape policy. If our results are valid also in other countries, suggesting that the social values differ significantly between agricultural landscape elements and between their environmental qualities, the inefficiencies caused by uniform payments may be a large, multinational problem.

The results in this study should be of relevance for the future use of CE for the assessment of private preferences for public goods related to the agricultural landscape in general and to the use of models, allowing for heterogeneous preferences for such goods in particular. One aspect of the present study is that respondents accustomed to one state of the agricultural landscape corresponding to an attribute level in the experiment are separated from those that are not. This was done by including reference points in order to capture familiarity with states of the investigated attributes. Approximately half of the included reference point effects were significant – thus reducing the degree of unobserved heterogeneity. Consequently, it cannot be rejected that people may value certain landscape management alternatives based on their reference levels. Our findings can be interpreted in the light of conventional as well as reference-dependent utility theory. In any case, this is a finding worth recognising in forming policy design – to be efficient the policy needs further understanding on the formation of private references. A further dynamic perspective is also warranted: the demand of landscape services may adjust over time as the landscape changes. People may be willing to sustain attributes, or accept states of the attributes that they are accustomed to, or actively relate to.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to express their gratitude to The Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation for financing this study, and to all respondents who have contributed in the surveys.

Notes

 1. SEK, Swedish crown; 1 SEK ≈ 0.10 EUR (2009).

 2. Swedish Board of Agriculture, Swedish National Heritage Board and Swedish Environmental Protection Agency.

 3. To capture the Total Economic Value (TEV) of the agricultural landscape, the attributes were designed to cover the relevant use and non-use values, as well as biodiversity, cultural heritage values, etc.

 4. From the full factorial design, sets with completely dominating alternatives were deleted. Moreover, we wanted to avoid ‘too dominant’ choice sets. This was done by calculating so-called code sums for each option (Wiley Citation1978). To calculate the code sum, we arrange the levels of the attributes from worst to best, the lowest attribute level being assigned a value of 0, the next 1 and so on. Thus, for a three-level attribute, the highest value is 2. The code sum is the sum of all these values for each option. By comparing the code sums, it is possible to get a simple indication of which alternatives are particularly dominant, although not completely dominant. This is clearly a crude approach, so for it to work reasonably well the utility difference between two levels should not differ too much across attributes.

 5. Carlsson et al. (Citation2007) tested the effect on MWTP using a survey with and without an opt-out alternative. They found that the inclusion of an opt-out alternative did not significantly affect the marginal WTP.

 6. The samples that the paper's results are based on are slightly over-represented by individuals who are women, older or have a university education. Men constitute 50.4% of the Swedish population of 20–74 years (SS, 2008), while the sample averages are 47–49%. The average age of the Swedish population (20–74 years) is 46.1 years (SS 2008), but 51 years in the samples. Approximately 34% of persons aged 20–64 years in Sweden have university education (SS 2008), compared to 38–44% in the samples. The differences between sample averages and the population mean are statistically significant. However, in an extended econometric model (not presented here) it was found that over-representation had a minor impact on the final estimates, since the average marginal utility of the attributes are just in a few cases statistically different for these socio-economic variables.

 7. In its original formulation, the reference point effect was defined in the context of choice under uncertainty, stating that the valuation of a change typically depends on whether the change is viewed as a gain or a loss, relative to a reference level.

 8. Closely related, but conceptually distinct from reference-dependent utility functions are habitat-formation models, see Dusenberry (1952), Pollak (Citation1970), and Ryder and Heal (Citation1973) for an exposition. While the utility function in the reference-dependent utility framework is defined over departures from a reference point, i.e. u = u(consumption - reference point), habitat-formation models include the idea that utility from current consumption (tastes) can be affected by the level of past consumption, i.e. u = u(consumptiont, consumptiont-1, consumptiont-2 …).

 9. The way we define the reference points is close to the classical discrimination between use and non-use values. However, the reference-dependent utility framework allows for other interpretations, as displayed below when discussing the results. In short, it does not exclude the possibility that respondents makes their choices based on reference-points.

10. There are several alternatives to the assumption of normal distributed attribute coefficients. For example, lognormal distributed attribute coefficients would ensure a positive WTP distribution. However, in this study, such an assumption may be too conservative for most of the attributes since some respondent may dislike the attributes.

11. There are several stipulations for the payments, for example, payments can go to a point element object only if all field elements of the farm are cleared from brushwood or thicket (MA 2007b).

References

  • Alpizar , F. , Carlsson , F. and Martinsson , P. 2003 . Using choice experiments for non-market valuation . Economic issues , 8 : 83 – 110 .
  • Bonnieux , F. and LeGoffe , P. 1997 . Valuing the benefits of landscape restoration: a case study of the Cotentin in Lower-Normandy, France . Journal of environmental management , 50 ( 3 ) : 321 – 333 .
  • Bruce , G. S.H. , Johnson , E. J. and Fader , P. S. 1993 . Modelling loss aversion and reference dependence effects on brand choice . Marketing science , 12 ( 4 ) : 378 – 394 .
  • Bullock , C. H. and Kay , J. 1997 . Preservation and change in the Central Southern Upland landscape in Scotland: the public benefits of grazing management . Journal of environmental planning and management , 40 ( 3 ) : 315 – 334 .
  • Campbell , D. W. , Hutchinson , G. and Scarpa , R. 2006 . Using discrete choice experiments to derive individual-specific WTP estimates for landscape improvements under agri-environmental schemes: evidence from the rural environment protection scheme in Ireland Working paper. Milano: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei
  • Carlsson , F. , Frykblom , P. and Lagerkvist , C. J. 2005 . Using cheap talk as a test of validity in choice experiments . Economics letters , 89 : 147 – 152 .
  • Carlsson , F. , Frykblom , P. and Lagerkvist , C. J. 2007 . Consumer willingness to pay for farm animal welfare: mobile abattoirs versus transportation to slaughter . European review of agricultural economics , 34 ( 3 ) : 321 – 344 .
  • Colson , F. and Stenger-Letheux , A. 1996 . Evaluation contingente et paysages agricoles. Application au bocage de Loire-Atlantique . Cahiers d'economie et sociologie rurales , 39–40 : 151 – 177 .
  • Dachary-Bernard , J. 2004 . Une évaluation économique du paysage. Une application de la méthode des choix multi-attributs aux Monts d'Arrée . Économie et statistique , 373 : 57 – 80 .
  • Drake , L. 1992 . The non-market values of the Swedish agricultural landscape . European review of agricultural economics , 19 : 351 – 364 .
  • Dramstad , W. E. 2006 . Relationships between visual landscape preferences and map-based indicators of landscape structure . Landscape and urban planning , 78 ( 4 ) : 465 – 474 .
  • Duesenberry , J. 1952 . Income, saving, and the theory of consumer behaviour , Cambridge, MA : Harvard University Press .
  • EEA (European Environment Agency) . 1995 . Europe's environment – the Dobris Assessment Copenhagen
  • Fleischer , A. and Tsur , Y. 2000 . Measuring the recreational value of agricultural landscape . European review of agricultural economics , 27 ( 3 ) : 385 – 398 .
  • Freeman , A. M. 2003 . The measurement of environmental and resource values. Theory and methods , 2nd ed , Washington DC : Resources for the Future .
  • Garrod , G. D. and Willis , K. G. 1995 . Valuing the benefits of the South Downs Environmentally Sensitive Area . Journal of agricultural economics , 46 ( 2 ) : 160 – 173 .
  • Goldstein , D. G. and Gigerenzer , G. 2002 . Models of ecological rationality: the recognition heuristic . Psychological review , 109 ( 1 ) : 75 – 90 .
  • Hanemann , W. M. 1984 . Welfare Evaluations in Contingent Valuation with discrete responses . American Journal of Agricultural Economics , 66 : 332 – 341 .
  • Hanley , N. 1998 . “ Valuing the countryside: rural land use policy evaluation using contingent valuation in the UK ” . In Heritage, the arts and the environment: pricing the priceless , 17 – 38 . Edinburgh University Press .
  • Hanley , N. 1998 . Contingent valuation versus choice experiments: estimating the benefits of Environmentally Sensitive Areas in Scotland . Journal of agricultural economics , 49 ( 1 ) : 1 – 15 .
  • Hasund , K. P. 1998 . “ Valuable landscapes and reliable estimates ” . In The economics of landscape and wildlife conservation , Edited by: Dabbert , S. 65 – 83 . Wallingford : CAB International .
  • Hensher , D. A and Greene , W. H. 2003 . The mixed logit model: the state of practice . Transportation , 30 ( 2 ) : 133 – 176 .
  • Hodge , I. and McNally , S. 1998 . Evaluating the environmentally sensitive areas: the value of rural environments and policy relevance . Journal of rural studies , 14 ( 3 ) : 357 – 367 .
  • Hu , W. , Adamowicz , W. L. and Veeman , M. M. 2006 . Labeling context and reference point effects in models of food attribute demand . American journal of agricultural economics , 88 ( 4 ) : 1034 – 1049 .
  • Hägerhäll , C. 1999 . The experience of pastoral landscapes Thesis (PhD), Agraria 182, Acta Universitatis Agriculturae Sueciae. Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences
  • Ihse , M. 1995 . Swedish agricultural landscapes – patterns and changes during the last 50 years, studied by aerial photos . Landscape and urban planning , 31 ( 1–3 ) : 21 – 37 .
  • Jonasson , L. and Kumm , K.-I. 2006 . Betesmarkerna efter 2003 års jordbruksreform – hot och möjligheter. 2006:3 , Jönköping : Jordbruksverket [Swedish Board of Agriculture] .
  • Kahneman , D. and Tversky , A. 1979 . Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk . Econometrica , 47 ( 2 ) : 263 – 292 .
  • Kuhfeld , W. 2001 . Multinomial logit, discrete choice modeling. An introduction to designing choice experiment and collecting, processing and analyzing choice data with SAS , TS – 643 . SAS Institute .
  • Louviere , J. J. 1988 . Analyzing decision making: metric conjoint analysis , Newbury Park : Sage .
  • Louviere , J.J. , Honsher , D. A. and Swait , J.D. 2000 . Stated choice methods , Cambridge University Press .
  • MA, Ministry of Agriculture [Jordbruksdepartementet] . 2003 . Ett levande kulturlandskap SOU 2003:105, Stockholm
  • MA, Ministry of Agriculture [Jordbruksdepartementet] . 2007a . Landsbygdsprogram för Sverige 2007–2013. [The Swedish Rural Development Programme 2007 – 2013], Stockholm
  • MA, Ministry of Agriculture [Jordbruksdepartementet] . 2007b . SFS 2007:481. Förordning (2007:481) om stöd för landsbygdsutvecklingsåtgärder [online] Available from: http://www2.notisum.com/Pub/Doc.aspx?url=rnp/sls/lag/20070481.htm [Accessed 1 February 2009]
  • Miljömålsrådet, 2008. Miljömålen-nu är det bràttom. Miljömålsrådets utvärdering av miljömålen 2008. Stockholm.
  • Pollak , R. A. 1970 . Habitat formation and dynamic demand functions . Journal of political economy , 78 ( 4 ) : 745 – 763 .
  • Pruckner , G. J. 1995 . Agricultural landscape cultivation in Austria: an application of the CVM . European review of agricultural economics , 22 ( 2 ) : 173 – 190 .
  • Randall , A. 1972 . Market solutions to externality problems: theory and practice . American journal of agricultural economics , 54 ( 2 ) : 175 – 183 .
  • Randall , A. 1988 . “ Market failure and the efficiency of irrigated agriculture ” . In Efficiency in irrigation: the conjunctive use of surface and groundwater resources , Edited by: O'Mara , G. T. 21 – 30 . Washington DC : The World Bank .
  • Randall , A. 2002 . Valuing the outputs of multifunctional agriculture . European review of agricultural economics , 29 ( 3 ) : 289 – 307 .
  • Robertson , G. , Eknert , B. and Ihse , M. 1990 . Habitat analysis from infrared aerial photographs and the conservation of birds in Swedish agricultural landscapes . Ambio , 19 ( 4 ) : 195 – 203 .
  • Ryder , H. E. and Heal , G. M. 1973 . Optimal growth with intertemporally dependent preferences . Review of economic studies , 40 : 1 – 33 .
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2005a . Ängs- och betesmarksinventeringen 2002–2004 2005:1. Jönköping
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2005b . Indikatorsystem för ängs– och betesmarker 2005:8, Jönköping
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2005c . Indikatorsystem för småbiotoper 2005:7. Jönköping
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2005d . Svenskt jordbruk i siffror 1800–2004 2005:6. Jönköping
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2006 . Kulturhistoriska bidrag och särdrag – uppföljning och utvärdering av miljöersättningen till nature- och kulturmiljöer 2006:10. Jönköping
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2007 . SJVFS 2007:42
  • SBA (Swedish Board of Agriculture) [Jordbruksverket] . 2008 . Värdering av betesmarker 2008:26. Jönköping
  • SEPA (Swedish Environmental Protection Agency) [Naturvårdsverket] . 2006 . Sweden's 16 Environmental Goals Stockholm. [online] Available from: http://www.naturvardsverket.se/sv/Sveriges-miljomal-for-ett–hallbart-samhalle/ [Accessed 1 February 2009].
  • SNHB (Swedish National Heritage Board) [Riksantikvarieämbetet] . 1999 . Kulturarvet och miljön. Miljömålen i Sverige Stockholm
  • SSIC (Swedish Species Information Centre) [ArtDatabanken] . 2005 . Rödlistade växter i Sverige 2005 [Swedish Red Data Book of Plants 2005] Uppsala
  • SS (Statistics Sweden) . 2008 . Statistical yearbook of Sweden 2008 Stockholm
  • Samuelson , P. A. 1954 . The pure theory of public expenditure . The review of economic statistics , 36 : 387 – 389 .
  • Samuelson , W. and Zeckhauser , R. 1988 . Status quo bias in decision making . Journal of risk and uncertainty , 1 : 7 – 59 .
  • Sandström , A. and Klang , L. 2007 . Landskapselement med miljöersättning – en intervjustudie om regionala och lokala erfarenheter av landskapselementens skötsel i åkermark och betesmark. 2007:5 , Jönköping : Swedish Board of Agriculture .
  • Santos , J. M.L. 1998 . The economic valuation of landscape change , Cheltenham and Northampton : Edward Elgar Publishing .
  • Svensson , R. 1988 . Floravård i jordbrukslandskapet . Svensk botanisk tidskrift , 82 : 458 – 465 .
  • Train , K. 2003 . Discrete choice methods with simulation , New York : Cambridge University Press .
  • Willis , K.G. and Garrod , G.D. 1991 . Landscape values: a contingent valuation approach and case study of the Yorkshire Dales National Park , Newcastle upon Tyne : Department of Agricultural Economics and Food Marketing, 21, University of Newcastle upon Tyne .
  • Willis , K. G. , Garrod , G. D. and Saunders , C. M. 1995 . Benefits of Environmentally Sensitive Area policy in England: a contingent valuation assessment . Journal of environmental management , 44 : 105 – 125 .
  • Wiley , J. B. 1978 . Selecting pareto optimal subsets from multi-attribute alternatives . Advances in consumer research , 5 : 171 – 174 .
  • Young , A. G. and Clarke , G. M. 2000 . Genetics, demography and viability of fragmented populations , Cambridge University Press .
  • Yong–Kwang , S. and Chang-Gil , K. 2006 . Economic valuation of environmentally friendly agriculture for improving environmental quality . Journal of rural development , 29 ( 4 ) : 73 – 86 .
  • Öckinger , E. and Smith , H. G. 2007 . Semi-natural pastures as population sources for pollinating insects in agricultural landscapes . Journal of applied ecology , 44 : 50 – 59 .

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.